Beat the Press

Beat the press por Dean Baker

Beat the Press is Dean Baker's commentary on economic reporting. He is a Senior Economist at the Center for Economic and Policy Research (CEPR). To never miss a post, subscribe to a weekly email roundup of Beat the Press. Please also consider supporting the blog on Patreon.

The Washington Post, which relied on David Lereah, the chief economist of the National Association of Realtors, as its main and often only source on the housing market, remains seriously confused about housing. An article on efforts by the Obama administration to push banks to increase lending implied that the situation of the bubble years were normal. It told readers: "Before the crisis, about 40 percent of home buyers were first-time purchasers. That’s down to 30 percent, according to the National Association of Realtors." Of course in the bubble years many people were buying homes with zero or even less than zero down payments. (Many borrowers were able to borrow more than the sale price of the home.) It is bizarre that anyone would use this period as a basis of comparison. The current rate of new homebuyers is closer to the historic norm. The piece later tells readers: "One reason, according to policymakers [anyone with a name?], is that as young people move out of their parents’ homes and start their own households, they will be forced to rent rather than buy, meaning less construction and housing activity. Given housing’s role in building up a family’s wealth, that could have long-lasting consequences." Actually renting also increases the demand for housing. Units switch back and forth all the time between being rental units and ownership units (30 percent of rental units are single-family homes). As a practical matter, the main factor depressing construction right now is the fact that the country continues to have a near record vacancy rate. The vacancy rate is the same whether a family is renting or owning.
The Washington Post, which relied on David Lereah, the chief economist of the National Association of Realtors, as its main and often only source on the housing market, remains seriously confused about housing. An article on efforts by the Obama administration to push banks to increase lending implied that the situation of the bubble years were normal. It told readers: "Before the crisis, about 40 percent of home buyers were first-time purchasers. That’s down to 30 percent, according to the National Association of Realtors." Of course in the bubble years many people were buying homes with zero or even less than zero down payments. (Many borrowers were able to borrow more than the sale price of the home.) It is bizarre that anyone would use this period as a basis of comparison. The current rate of new homebuyers is closer to the historic norm. The piece later tells readers: "One reason, according to policymakers [anyone with a name?], is that as young people move out of their parents’ homes and start their own households, they will be forced to rent rather than buy, meaning less construction and housing activity. Given housing’s role in building up a family’s wealth, that could have long-lasting consequences." Actually renting also increases the demand for housing. Units switch back and forth all the time between being rental units and ownership units (30 percent of rental units are single-family homes). As a practical matter, the main factor depressing construction right now is the fact that the country continues to have a near record vacancy rate. The vacancy rate is the same whether a family is renting or owning.

It’s always fun when major news outlets look at the same economic situation and come up with directly opposite conclusions. Hence we had the Washington Post telling readers,

“European industry flocks to U.S. to take advantage of cheaper gas,”

on the same day that the NYT had a piece headlined,

“Rumors of a cheap-energy jobs boom remain just that.”

When it comes to data, the NYT clearly wins the case. The Post piece has people whining about high gas prices in Europe, but little evidence of jobs actually coming to the United States. The NYT piece makes the obvious point that in most industries gas prices are a small share of total costs. Even in the most energy intensive industries labor is almost certain to be a higher share of total costs than natural gas.

Furthermore, the drop in gas prices in the U.S. is likely to be reflected elsewhere. This means that third countries that have cheaper labor, like Mexico, are also likely to have comparable natural gas prices.

In fact, the large differences in prices between the United States and Europe that are the central feature of the Post article are not likely to persist since the United States is likely to export surplus gas to Europe. The Post notes the likely impact of exports on U.S. natural gas prices, but it doesn’t acknowledge their likely impact on prices in Europe. While the Post may have missed this tendency towards equalizing prices through trade, manufacturers that are considering moving their operations almost certainly are aware of this likely outcome.  

It’s always fun when major news outlets look at the same economic situation and come up with directly opposite conclusions. Hence we had the Washington Post telling readers,

“European industry flocks to U.S. to take advantage of cheaper gas,”

on the same day that the NYT had a piece headlined,

“Rumors of a cheap-energy jobs boom remain just that.”

When it comes to data, the NYT clearly wins the case. The Post piece has people whining about high gas prices in Europe, but little evidence of jobs actually coming to the United States. The NYT piece makes the obvious point that in most industries gas prices are a small share of total costs. Even in the most energy intensive industries labor is almost certain to be a higher share of total costs than natural gas.

Furthermore, the drop in gas prices in the U.S. is likely to be reflected elsewhere. This means that third countries that have cheaper labor, like Mexico, are also likely to have comparable natural gas prices.

In fact, the large differences in prices between the United States and Europe that are the central feature of the Post article are not likely to persist since the United States is likely to export surplus gas to Europe. The Post notes the likely impact of exports on U.S. natural gas prices, but it doesn’t acknowledge their likely impact on prices in Europe. While the Post may have missed this tendency towards equalizing prices through trade, manufacturers that are considering moving their operations almost certainly are aware of this likely outcome.  

The Washington Post ran a piece titled, “the April Fool’s Economy,” that began by telling readers:

“The economic recovery has faked us out before.”

It continued:

“In 2012 and 2011, seemingly strong momentum in the first half of the year gave way to summer slumps. Will the third try be the charm? Or is this just another prank — one that’s getting old fast.”

Huh?

In 2011 the economy grew at a 2.5 percent annual rate in the second quarter and just a 0.1 percent rate in the first quarter for a first half average of 1.3 percent. This is way below the trend growth rate, which is between 2.2 percent and 2.5 percent. Job growth was a bit better, averaging 196,000 a month, but that’s only slightly better than the average of 180,000 jobs a month for all of 2011 and 2012. It’s not clear what people who saw strong momentum in the first half of 2011 could have been looking at.

The beginning of 2012 was somewhat stronger, with job growth averaging 240,000 a month from October to March. GDP growth also looked better over this period, growing 4.1 percent in the 4th quarter and 2.0 percent in the first quarter. But serious analysts noted at the time that the job growth data was inflated by better than usual winter weather, which would lead to slower growth in the spring.

Maybe if the Post relied on analysts with a better understanding of the economy it wouldn’t be so susceptible to April Fool’s jokes.

The Washington Post ran a piece titled, “the April Fool’s Economy,” that began by telling readers:

“The economic recovery has faked us out before.”

It continued:

“In 2012 and 2011, seemingly strong momentum in the first half of the year gave way to summer slumps. Will the third try be the charm? Or is this just another prank — one that’s getting old fast.”

Huh?

In 2011 the economy grew at a 2.5 percent annual rate in the second quarter and just a 0.1 percent rate in the first quarter for a first half average of 1.3 percent. This is way below the trend growth rate, which is between 2.2 percent and 2.5 percent. Job growth was a bit better, averaging 196,000 a month, but that’s only slightly better than the average of 180,000 jobs a month for all of 2011 and 2012. It’s not clear what people who saw strong momentum in the first half of 2011 could have been looking at.

The beginning of 2012 was somewhat stronger, with job growth averaging 240,000 a month from October to March. GDP growth also looked better over this period, growing 4.1 percent in the 4th quarter and 2.0 percent in the first quarter. But serious analysts noted at the time that the job growth data was inflated by better than usual winter weather, which would lead to slower growth in the spring.

Maybe if the Post relied on analysts with a better understanding of the economy it wouldn’t be so susceptible to April Fool’s jokes.

The austerity gang who are trying to wreck Europe’s economy must be furious at the NYT. They managed to get the unemployment rate up to 12.0 percent, a truly historic achievement. Europe had not seen unemployment reach this level since the Great Depression, more than 70 years ago.

However in its article reporting on the new data, NYT told readers:

“The European labor market has now declined for 22 straight months, making this the worst downturn since the early 1990s, Jennifer McKeown, an economist in London with Capital Economics, wrote in a note.”

Come on, unemployment in the euro zone countries peaked at 10.9 percent in 1994. That downturn can’t come close to the damage done by the current austerity crew. I trust that they will demand a correction from the NYT.

The austerity gang who are trying to wreck Europe’s economy must be furious at the NYT. They managed to get the unemployment rate up to 12.0 percent, a truly historic achievement. Europe had not seen unemployment reach this level since the Great Depression, more than 70 years ago.

However in its article reporting on the new data, NYT told readers:

“The European labor market has now declined for 22 straight months, making this the worst downturn since the early 1990s, Jennifer McKeown, an economist in London with Capital Economics, wrote in a note.”

Come on, unemployment in the euro zone countries peaked at 10.9 percent in 1994. That downturn can’t come close to the damage done by the current austerity crew. I trust that they will demand a correction from the NYT.

The Post told readers that drug companies would try to punish India for a Supreme Court ruling that denied Novartis, a Swiss drug company, a patent for its cancer drug, Glivec. The court determined that the drug involved only a minor modification of an earlier invention and therefore was not entitled to a patent monopoly. As a result, generic producers in India are able to produce and sell the drug for less than one-tenth its patent protected price.

In discussing the implications of the decision, the piece told readers:

“Many international drug companies have said that the Novartis trial was crucial to addressing the rapidly growing perception around the world that India’s patent protection system for drugs is weak. Such perceptions, many patent advocates say, will adversely affect foreign investment in India, especially by global drug companies that are eyeing the huge market in this nation of 1.2 billion people.”

There is no economic reason that this court decision would affect the drug industry’s investment at all. Drug companies will get the exact same patent protection for their drugs in India and every other country in the world regardless of where they conduct their research. If India was the most profitable place for a drug company to conduct its research before this patent decision then it is still the most profitable place for a drug company to conduct its research.

The only basis for shifting investment would be to punish India, presumably with the hope that if enough investment shifts India may change its patent laws. This means that drug companies and their shareholders (e.g. university and foundation endowments and public sector pension funds) are foregoing profits today in the hope that they can inflict enough punishment on India to change its patent laws. That is a striking claim and the Washington Post did its readers a service by calling it to public attention, even if the Post may not have understood the implications of what it printed.

The Post told readers that drug companies would try to punish India for a Supreme Court ruling that denied Novartis, a Swiss drug company, a patent for its cancer drug, Glivec. The court determined that the drug involved only a minor modification of an earlier invention and therefore was not entitled to a patent monopoly. As a result, generic producers in India are able to produce and sell the drug for less than one-tenth its patent protected price.

In discussing the implications of the decision, the piece told readers:

“Many international drug companies have said that the Novartis trial was crucial to addressing the rapidly growing perception around the world that India’s patent protection system for drugs is weak. Such perceptions, many patent advocates say, will adversely affect foreign investment in India, especially by global drug companies that are eyeing the huge market in this nation of 1.2 billion people.”

There is no economic reason that this court decision would affect the drug industry’s investment at all. Drug companies will get the exact same patent protection for their drugs in India and every other country in the world regardless of where they conduct their research. If India was the most profitable place for a drug company to conduct its research before this patent decision then it is still the most profitable place for a drug company to conduct its research.

The only basis for shifting investment would be to punish India, presumably with the hope that if enough investment shifts India may change its patent laws. This means that drug companies and their shareholders (e.g. university and foundation endowments and public sector pension funds) are foregoing profits today in the hope that they can inflict enough punishment on India to change its patent laws. That is a striking claim and the Washington Post did its readers a service by calling it to public attention, even if the Post may not have understood the implications of what it printed.

Anyone who thought David Stockman’s screed in the Sunday NYT against fiat money and the New Deal was an isolated incident has to contend with Roger Farmer’s call for bringing back the housing bubble in the Financial Times. It’s obviously nutty season at the major news outlets.

So boys and girls, get out those columns calling for a universal currency, the switch to seashell standard, and 28 cent a gallon gasoline. The major media outlets are waiting.

Anyone who thought David Stockman’s screed in the Sunday NYT against fiat money and the New Deal was an isolated incident has to contend with Roger Farmer’s call for bringing back the housing bubble in the Financial Times. It’s obviously nutty season at the major news outlets.

So boys and girls, get out those columns calling for a universal currency, the switch to seashell standard, and 28 cent a gallon gasoline. The major media outlets are waiting.

Following in the footsteps of his colleague at the Post, Dylan Matthews, Robert Samuelson devoted a column to a new book on trade by Robert Lawrence, complaining that we don’t give enough credit to trade. I won’t rehash the basic points that Samuelson gets wrong. However it is probably worth going through the basic story as to how trade can lead to overall gains to the economy and yet hurt large groups of workers.

Suppose that we diverted 6 percent of the current flow of immigrants so that instead of being farmworkers and custodians they were doctors trained to U.S. standards. After a decade we would have an additional 800,000 doctors, roughly doubling the current supply. Let’s imagine that this cut their (service adjusted) average pay in half to $125,000 a year.

In this story, we would save $100 billion a year in what we pay doctors. This would imply an enormous benefit to the economy in the form of lower health care costs.

Even doctors would benefit from having to pay less for health care for themselves and their families. Of course their savings on health care costs would be swamped in its impact on their living standards by their reduction in pay. (Maybe we could get some economists and economic columnists to tell the doctors that they are stupid for opposing trade agreements because of the huge savings they see on health care, just as they tell manufacturing workers that they are stupid for not appreciating the benefits of low cost imported manufactured goods.)

Anyhow, this is the basic story on trade in the U.S. over the last three decades. It has been designed to put non-college educated workers in direct competition with their counterparts in the developing world, while largely protecting the most highly educated workers. The predicted and actual result from this structure of trade is to reduce their wages, redistributing income to corporate profits and highly educated professionals.

 

Following in the footsteps of his colleague at the Post, Dylan Matthews, Robert Samuelson devoted a column to a new book on trade by Robert Lawrence, complaining that we don’t give enough credit to trade. I won’t rehash the basic points that Samuelson gets wrong. However it is probably worth going through the basic story as to how trade can lead to overall gains to the economy and yet hurt large groups of workers.

Suppose that we diverted 6 percent of the current flow of immigrants so that instead of being farmworkers and custodians they were doctors trained to U.S. standards. After a decade we would have an additional 800,000 doctors, roughly doubling the current supply. Let’s imagine that this cut their (service adjusted) average pay in half to $125,000 a year.

In this story, we would save $100 billion a year in what we pay doctors. This would imply an enormous benefit to the economy in the form of lower health care costs.

Even doctors would benefit from having to pay less for health care for themselves and their families. Of course their savings on health care costs would be swamped in its impact on their living standards by their reduction in pay. (Maybe we could get some economists and economic columnists to tell the doctors that they are stupid for opposing trade agreements because of the huge savings they see on health care, just as they tell manufacturing workers that they are stupid for not appreciating the benefits of low cost imported manufactured goods.)

Anyhow, this is the basic story on trade in the U.S. over the last three decades. It has been designed to put non-college educated workers in direct competition with their counterparts in the developing world, while largely protecting the most highly educated workers. The predicted and actual result from this structure of trade is to reduce their wages, redistributing income to corporate profits and highly educated professionals.

 

Numerology is usually held in low regard in intellectual circles. Unfortunately it is front and center in the debate over national economic policy. Many economists and political leaders tell the public that we have to keep the DEBT to GDP ratio (capitalized to show reverence) below some magical level. Greg Mankiw professes his adherence to the faith in the NYT on Sunday. The reason that either a specific number or a strict focus on debt to GDP ratios is viewed as silly by people who are not numerologists is that the DEBT to GDP ratio is a completely arbitrary number that tells us almost nothing about the financial health of the government or the country. First, the debt to GDP ratio is not even telling us anything about the burden of the debt on the government's finances. While the current debt to GDP ratio is relatively high, the ratio of interest payments to GDP is near a post-war low at 1 percent of GDP. (It's roughly 0.5 percent of GDP if we net out the money refunded to the Treasury by the Federal Reserve Board.) By contrast, the interest to GDP ratio was six times as large in the early 90s, at 3.0 percent of GDP. If we revere debt to GDP ratios, we will have the opportunity to buy back large amounts of long-term debt at steep discounts if interest rates rise later in the decade, as projected by the Congressional Budget Office and others. This exercise would be pointless, since it leaves the interest burden unchanged, but it should make the numerologists who dominate economic policy debates happy. (This debt buyback story is discussed here.)  
Numerology is usually held in low regard in intellectual circles. Unfortunately it is front and center in the debate over national economic policy. Many economists and political leaders tell the public that we have to keep the DEBT to GDP ratio (capitalized to show reverence) below some magical level. Greg Mankiw professes his adherence to the faith in the NYT on Sunday. The reason that either a specific number or a strict focus on debt to GDP ratios is viewed as silly by people who are not numerologists is that the DEBT to GDP ratio is a completely arbitrary number that tells us almost nothing about the financial health of the government or the country. First, the debt to GDP ratio is not even telling us anything about the burden of the debt on the government's finances. While the current debt to GDP ratio is relatively high, the ratio of interest payments to GDP is near a post-war low at 1 percent of GDP. (It's roughly 0.5 percent of GDP if we net out the money refunded to the Treasury by the Federal Reserve Board.) By contrast, the interest to GDP ratio was six times as large in the early 90s, at 3.0 percent of GDP. If we revere debt to GDP ratios, we will have the opportunity to buy back large amounts of long-term debt at steep discounts if interest rates rise later in the decade, as projected by the Congressional Budget Office and others. This exercise would be pointless, since it leaves the interest burden unchanged, but it should make the numerologists who dominate economic policy debates happy. (This debt buyback story is discussed here.)  

It’s always nice when a major news outlet picks up on work by CEPR, even if it takes a year and some other economist to produce similar findings. Therefore, I was naturally happy to see this piece in the Wall Street Journal reporting that almost 300,000 college educated workers are earning the minimum wage.

The WSJ piece is based on a new paper by three Canadian economists that finds that many college educated workers are employed at jobs that don’t require college degrees. This is bad news not only for the college educated workers, but also for less-educated workers who are displaced by these college educated workers.

My colleagues at CEPR, John Schmitt and Janelle Jones, had done a short paper last April pointing out that minimum wage workers were much more likely to be college educated and have considerably more work experience than in prior decades. I’m glad to see that the WSJ has finally discovered this news.

It’s always nice when a major news outlet picks up on work by CEPR, even if it takes a year and some other economist to produce similar findings. Therefore, I was naturally happy to see this piece in the Wall Street Journal reporting that almost 300,000 college educated workers are earning the minimum wage.

The WSJ piece is based on a new paper by three Canadian economists that finds that many college educated workers are employed at jobs that don’t require college degrees. This is bad news not only for the college educated workers, but also for less-educated workers who are displaced by these college educated workers.

My colleagues at CEPR, John Schmitt and Janelle Jones, had done a short paper last April pointing out that minimum wage workers were much more likely to be college educated and have considerably more work experience than in prior decades. I’m glad to see that the WSJ has finally discovered this news.

Imagine getting paid to write things on economics that don't make sense for the New York Times? That job may not exist if Thomas Friedman didn't invent it. Hence the headline of his Sunday column, "Need a Job? Invent It."  As Friedman tells readers, you need to create your own job because: "there is increasingly no such thing as a high-wage, middle-skilled job — the thing that sustained the middle class in the last generation. Now there is only a high-wage, high-skilled job. Every middle-class job today is being pulled up, out or down faster than ever. That is, it either requires more skill or can be done by more people around the world or is being buried — made obsolete — faster than ever." One part of this story is just wrong and the other part is at best misleading. The wrong part is about jobs being made obsolete "faster than ever." The Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) actually measures the rate at which jobs are becoming obsolete, it's called "productivity growth." Over the last five years productivity growth in the non-farm business sector has averaged 1.6 percent annually. That's probably somewhat depressed as a result of the downturn, but even if we go back to 2002 we still only get up to 1.8 percent annually. That's well below the 2.8 percent annual rate from 1947 to 1973.
Imagine getting paid to write things on economics that don't make sense for the New York Times? That job may not exist if Thomas Friedman didn't invent it. Hence the headline of his Sunday column, "Need a Job? Invent It."  As Friedman tells readers, you need to create your own job because: "there is increasingly no such thing as a high-wage, middle-skilled job — the thing that sustained the middle class in the last generation. Now there is only a high-wage, high-skilled job. Every middle-class job today is being pulled up, out or down faster than ever. That is, it either requires more skill or can be done by more people around the world or is being buried — made obsolete — faster than ever." One part of this story is just wrong and the other part is at best misleading. The wrong part is about jobs being made obsolete "faster than ever." The Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) actually measures the rate at which jobs are becoming obsolete, it's called "productivity growth." Over the last five years productivity growth in the non-farm business sector has averaged 1.6 percent annually. That's probably somewhat depressed as a result of the downturn, but even if we go back to 2002 we still only get up to 1.8 percent annually. That's well below the 2.8 percent annual rate from 1947 to 1973.

Want to search in the archives?

¿Quieres buscar en los archivos?

Click Here Haga clic aquí