Beat the Press

Beat the press por Dean Baker

Beat the Press is Dean Baker's commentary on economic reporting. He is a Senior Economist at the Center for Economic and Policy Research (CEPR). To never miss a post, subscribe to a weekly email roundup of Beat the Press. Please also consider supporting the blog on Patreon.

For some reason, there seems to be a big market in efforts to confuse the public about the relationship between unemployment and the trade deficit. Robert Samuelson gives us yet another example in his column today. "By now, it must be obvious that US trade deficits are connected loosely, if at all, with the unemployment rate, which is now 3.9 percent — the lowest since 2000. Meanwhile, the US trade deficit in 2017 was $566 billion. "The explanation for the apparent paradox is the dollar’s role as the major international currency, used to conduct trade and investment among many (non-US) countries. The extra demand for dollars raises its exchange rate, making U.S. exports costlier and imports cheaper. The result is a structural U.S. trade deficit." This one makes pretty much zero sense. First of all, pointing to the low unemployment rate coinciding with a large trade deficit as evidence there is no link between unemployment and a trade deficit makes as much sense as pointing to a very underweight person suffering from the late stage cancer as an argument against any link between being seriously overweight and bad health. This isn not a serious argument. A trade deficit reduces demand in the economy. It means that some of our spending is creating demand in Europe or Mexico, rather than in the United States. Other things equal, that means less demand in the United States and higher unemployment. We can offset this lost demand with additional demand in the United States. We can have large budget deficits, as we do now. And we can have bubbles as we did in the late 1990s with the stock bubble and in the last decade with the housing bubble. That is why we can have a large trade deficit and low unemployment. It really is not hard.
For some reason, there seems to be a big market in efforts to confuse the public about the relationship between unemployment and the trade deficit. Robert Samuelson gives us yet another example in his column today. "By now, it must be obvious that US trade deficits are connected loosely, if at all, with the unemployment rate, which is now 3.9 percent — the lowest since 2000. Meanwhile, the US trade deficit in 2017 was $566 billion. "The explanation for the apparent paradox is the dollar’s role as the major international currency, used to conduct trade and investment among many (non-US) countries. The extra demand for dollars raises its exchange rate, making U.S. exports costlier and imports cheaper. The result is a structural U.S. trade deficit." This one makes pretty much zero sense. First of all, pointing to the low unemployment rate coinciding with a large trade deficit as evidence there is no link between unemployment and a trade deficit makes as much sense as pointing to a very underweight person suffering from the late stage cancer as an argument against any link between being seriously overweight and bad health. This isn not a serious argument. A trade deficit reduces demand in the economy. It means that some of our spending is creating demand in Europe or Mexico, rather than in the United States. Other things equal, that means less demand in the United States and higher unemployment. We can offset this lost demand with additional demand in the United States. We can have large budget deficits, as we do now. And we can have bubbles as we did in the late 1990s with the stock bubble and in the last decade with the housing bubble. That is why we can have a large trade deficit and low unemployment. It really is not hard.

Peter Goodman had a very good NYT piece detailing how budget cutbacks are undermining the welfare state in the United Kingdom. However, at one point the piece warns that the UK’s experience could be a wider warning for a future where “robots [are] substituting for human labor.”

Actually, the UK’s problem has been just the opposite. It has had extremely low productivity growth. Since the Great Recession, productivity growth has averaged less than 1.0 percent annually according to the OECD. This weak growth can actually provide some basis for an argument for austerity (not much, if workers had more bargaining power and higher pay, the country might see more rapid productivity growth). If productivity growth had been more rapid, then the government could easily spend more money without any fears of inflation.

Peter Goodman had a very good NYT piece detailing how budget cutbacks are undermining the welfare state in the United Kingdom. However, at one point the piece warns that the UK’s experience could be a wider warning for a future where “robots [are] substituting for human labor.”

Actually, the UK’s problem has been just the opposite. It has had extremely low productivity growth. Since the Great Recession, productivity growth has averaged less than 1.0 percent annually according to the OECD. This weak growth can actually provide some basis for an argument for austerity (not much, if workers had more bargaining power and higher pay, the country might see more rapid productivity growth). If productivity growth had been more rapid, then the government could easily spend more money without any fears of inflation.

The headline of the Washington Post article should have us all worried, “America has a massive truck driver shortage. Here’s why few want an $80,000 job.” That sounds pretty dramatic.

The article does begin by telling us about Joyce Brenny, who runs a trucking business in Minnesota, who supposedly pays many of her drivers more than $80,000 a year. (It doesn’t indicate if she is the source for this number.) However, folks who read a few paragraphs down discover:

“A few drivers told The Washington Post that they earn $100,000, but many said their annual pay is less than $50,000 (government statistics say median pay for the industry is $42,000).”

In other words, if Ms. Brenny is actually paying her drivers $80,000 a year, she is very much an outlier. The typical driver makes barely half of this amount, which is a likely explanation for any shortage of truckers that might exist. (For a point of reference, the annual pay of a truck driver would be about half of what many CEOs earn in a day and roughly one-tenth of a what a top line politician would get for a one-hour speech to a major bank.)

It also seems that folks who run trucking companies have a hard time understanding how labor markets are supposed to work. Here is the average hourly wage, adjusted for inflation, in the trucking industry:

Trucking Industry: Average Hourly Wage, Adjusted for Inflation

trucker 3

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

According to the Bureau of Labor Statistics, the average hourly pay for truck drivers is actually down from its level of two years ago. While it is up by roughly 5.0 percent from its level a decade ago, it is down by more than 7.0 percent from the peaks hit in the late 1990s.

This seems like yet one more case where we have employers whining about worker shortages because they are unwilling to pay the market wage. And, it seems the Washington Post is aggressively pushing the employers’ case even if it means misrepresenting the facts.

The headline of the Washington Post article should have us all worried, “America has a massive truck driver shortage. Here’s why few want an $80,000 job.” That sounds pretty dramatic.

The article does begin by telling us about Joyce Brenny, who runs a trucking business in Minnesota, who supposedly pays many of her drivers more than $80,000 a year. (It doesn’t indicate if she is the source for this number.) However, folks who read a few paragraphs down discover:

“A few drivers told The Washington Post that they earn $100,000, but many said their annual pay is less than $50,000 (government statistics say median pay for the industry is $42,000).”

In other words, if Ms. Brenny is actually paying her drivers $80,000 a year, she is very much an outlier. The typical driver makes barely half of this amount, which is a likely explanation for any shortage of truckers that might exist. (For a point of reference, the annual pay of a truck driver would be about half of what many CEOs earn in a day and roughly one-tenth of a what a top line politician would get for a one-hour speech to a major bank.)

It also seems that folks who run trucking companies have a hard time understanding how labor markets are supposed to work. Here is the average hourly wage, adjusted for inflation, in the trucking industry:

Trucking Industry: Average Hourly Wage, Adjusted for Inflation

trucker 3

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

According to the Bureau of Labor Statistics, the average hourly pay for truck drivers is actually down from its level of two years ago. While it is up by roughly 5.0 percent from its level a decade ago, it is down by more than 7.0 percent from the peaks hit in the late 1990s.

This seems like yet one more case where we have employers whining about worker shortages because they are unwilling to pay the market wage. And, it seems the Washington Post is aggressively pushing the employers’ case even if it means misrepresenting the facts.

Roger Lowenstein had a column in the Washington Post criticizing Elon Musk for his new contract as Tesla's CEO that could net him $50 billion. I see the story somewhat differently. Lowenstein essentially is blaming Musk for being incredibly greedy and not
Roger Lowenstein had a column in the Washington Post criticizing Elon Musk for his new contract as Tesla's CEO that could net him $50 billion. I see the story somewhat differently. Lowenstein essentially is blaming Musk for being incredibly greedy and not

Bret Stephens rightly takes Elon Musk to task for his buffoonish attacks on his critics, dubbing him “The Donald of Silicon Valley.” (I prefer my line, “the Donald Trump of futuristic entrepreneurs,” but the point is the same.) Like Trump, Musk apparently is unable to accept criticism and lashes out at the integrity and competence of his critics. Also like Trump, he is apparently unable to run a profitable company.

However, where Stephens goes badly astray is in telling his readers that electric cars are not a viable technology. China is expected to sell more than 1 million electric cars this year. It expects to be selling more than 7 million electric cars annually by 2025. It’s true that electric cars have substantial government subsidies in China, but this has been true of many technologies, such as the Internet.

Electric cars can clearly be very competitive in the near future with gas powered cars. They are clearly not decades away as Stephens tells readers.

Bret Stephens rightly takes Elon Musk to task for his buffoonish attacks on his critics, dubbing him “The Donald of Silicon Valley.” (I prefer my line, “the Donald Trump of futuristic entrepreneurs,” but the point is the same.) Like Trump, Musk apparently is unable to accept criticism and lashes out at the integrity and competence of his critics. Also like Trump, he is apparently unable to run a profitable company.

However, where Stephens goes badly astray is in telling his readers that electric cars are not a viable technology. China is expected to sell more than 1 million electric cars this year. It expects to be selling more than 7 million electric cars annually by 2025. It’s true that electric cars have substantial government subsidies in China, but this has been true of many technologies, such as the Internet.

Electric cars can clearly be very competitive in the near future with gas powered cars. They are clearly not decades away as Stephens tells readers.

We all know that protectionism is bad. If someone proposes a 20 percent tariff on steel or cars the news pages will be filled with economists and other serious sounding people hyperventilating about how this tax will devastate the economy. Unfortunately, these voices are completely absent from discussions of the much more costly protectionism that allows our broken health care system to rip us off for hundreds of billions annually, and cost lives.

NPR and ProPublica gave us a fascinating account of how our broken health care system operates. The basic story was that Aetna had a contract with a major hospital that allowed it to charge grossly excessive fees for some procedures. Apparently, Aetna didn’t mind the overbilling since it is able to pass its costs on to patients in a largely uncompetitive market. 

The piece is fascinating since the protagonist, Michael Frank, was an actuary with three decades of experience working with insurance companies. It describes in detail the effort he went through to try to get a clear explanation of why his bill was two or three times as high as the normal billing for a procedure he had done.

If anyone involved in the health care debate was committed to free trade, we would have a discussion of how this sort of abuse could be avoided if we facilitated foreign medical travel. If patients were routinely offered the opportunity to have this sort of procedure in high-quality facilities in other countries, with patients splitting the tens of thousands of dollars in savings (net of travel costs for themselves and a family member), it is likely that hospitals and insurers that engaged in this sort of price rigging would go out of business.

However, medical travel never features in discussions of trade. One can speculate on the reason, but it is almost certainly true that the reporters, economists, and political actors involved in trade debates have many more friends and relatives who benefit from the bloated health care system than work in manufacturing jobs.

 

Addendum

The International Federal of Health Plans has some data on relative prices. To take an example, it reports an average price for bypass surgery in the United States of $78,300. This compares to $24,100 in the U.K. and $14,600 in Spain. This sort of gap would leave plenty of room to cover airfare and hotel stays, and still leave plenty of money to put in the bank.

We all know that protectionism is bad. If someone proposes a 20 percent tariff on steel or cars the news pages will be filled with economists and other serious sounding people hyperventilating about how this tax will devastate the economy. Unfortunately, these voices are completely absent from discussions of the much more costly protectionism that allows our broken health care system to rip us off for hundreds of billions annually, and cost lives.

NPR and ProPublica gave us a fascinating account of how our broken health care system operates. The basic story was that Aetna had a contract with a major hospital that allowed it to charge grossly excessive fees for some procedures. Apparently, Aetna didn’t mind the overbilling since it is able to pass its costs on to patients in a largely uncompetitive market. 

The piece is fascinating since the protagonist, Michael Frank, was an actuary with three decades of experience working with insurance companies. It describes in detail the effort he went through to try to get a clear explanation of why his bill was two or three times as high as the normal billing for a procedure he had done.

If anyone involved in the health care debate was committed to free trade, we would have a discussion of how this sort of abuse could be avoided if we facilitated foreign medical travel. If patients were routinely offered the opportunity to have this sort of procedure in high-quality facilities in other countries, with patients splitting the tens of thousands of dollars in savings (net of travel costs for themselves and a family member), it is likely that hospitals and insurers that engaged in this sort of price rigging would go out of business.

However, medical travel never features in discussions of trade. One can speculate on the reason, but it is almost certainly true that the reporters, economists, and political actors involved in trade debates have many more friends and relatives who benefit from the bloated health care system than work in manufacturing jobs.

 

Addendum

The International Federal of Health Plans has some data on relative prices. To take an example, it reports an average price for bypass surgery in the United States of $78,300. This compares to $24,100 in the U.K. and $14,600 in Spain. This sort of gap would leave plenty of room to cover airfare and hotel stays, and still leave plenty of money to put in the bank.

The reporting of pay ratios between CEOs and median workers has drawn considerable attention to the enormous gap. Most of this has taken a moral tone, noting that would take the typical worker hundreds of years, or in some cases, more than a thousand years to earn as much as the company’s CEO gets in a year. While there are certainly important moral questions here, it is also important to ask a simple economic question.

Are the highly paid CEOs actually producing returns for shareholders? This is not an expression of concern for shareholders, the question is whether CEOs are actually worth their pay to the company or whether they are effectively ripping off shareholders. The latter story is plausible because it is difficult for a diverse group of shareholders to carefully monitor and control the conduct of a company, just as it is difficult for citizens to make sure that their city or state government is not ripping them off by having patronage jobs or sweetheart deals with well-connected contractors. 

The argument would be that the directors who most immediately monitor the CEOs have more allegiance to the CEOs and top management than the shareholders whom they ostensibly represent. This is a plausible story since directors who are renominated by their board win their elections more than 99 percent of the time. This means that directors would have little incentive to upset top management and their colleagues by asking annoying questions about whether CEOs get paid too much.

There is considerable research indicating that CEO pay does not reflect performance (measured as returns to shareholders), much of it summarized in Lucien Bebchuk and Jesse Fried’s book, Pay Without Performance. Jessica Schieder and I did a short piece that also supports this view, showing no drop in CEO pay at health insurers, after the Affordable Care Act ended tax deductibility for pay over $1 million.

This matters because it means that if rules of corporate governance were changed (these come from the government, not the market) to give shareholders more control over CEO pay, it is likely CEO pay would fall. This is not just a matter between rich CEOs and mostly rich shareholders. (Pension funds and middle-income people with 401(k)s also do own stock.)

Bloated CEO pay affects pay scales throughout the economy. If the CEO gets $30 million, the folks next in line likely get $10–15 million, and the third-tier executives may earn in the range of $1–2 million. Also, top executives in the non-profit sector also get bloated pay, often well over $1 million a year at universities and major charities.

By contrast, if CEOs were getting $2–$3 million a year, the next in line would likely be getting paychecks not much over $1 million, with the third tier settling for the high hundreds of thousands. And, the presidents of elite universities might also see paychecks in the high hundreds of thousands. And, if there was less pay for those at the top, there would be more pay for everyone else.

The point here is that this would not be a story of just saying we don’t like some people getting incredibly rich, while others get little (which may be the case), it would also be the story of getting the market to work better so that CEO pay reflects their actual performance, not their ability to take advantage of their insider position. There is no good argument for defending CEO pay that does not reflect performance unless you think it is a positive good that some people incredibly get rich while most workers get little benefit from the economy’s growth.

The reporting of pay ratios between CEOs and median workers has drawn considerable attention to the enormous gap. Most of this has taken a moral tone, noting that would take the typical worker hundreds of years, or in some cases, more than a thousand years to earn as much as the company’s CEO gets in a year. While there are certainly important moral questions here, it is also important to ask a simple economic question.

Are the highly paid CEOs actually producing returns for shareholders? This is not an expression of concern for shareholders, the question is whether CEOs are actually worth their pay to the company or whether they are effectively ripping off shareholders. The latter story is plausible because it is difficult for a diverse group of shareholders to carefully monitor and control the conduct of a company, just as it is difficult for citizens to make sure that their city or state government is not ripping them off by having patronage jobs or sweetheart deals with well-connected contractors. 

The argument would be that the directors who most immediately monitor the CEOs have more allegiance to the CEOs and top management than the shareholders whom they ostensibly represent. This is a plausible story since directors who are renominated by their board win their elections more than 99 percent of the time. This means that directors would have little incentive to upset top management and their colleagues by asking annoying questions about whether CEOs get paid too much.

There is considerable research indicating that CEO pay does not reflect performance (measured as returns to shareholders), much of it summarized in Lucien Bebchuk and Jesse Fried’s book, Pay Without Performance. Jessica Schieder and I did a short piece that also supports this view, showing no drop in CEO pay at health insurers, after the Affordable Care Act ended tax deductibility for pay over $1 million.

This matters because it means that if rules of corporate governance were changed (these come from the government, not the market) to give shareholders more control over CEO pay, it is likely CEO pay would fall. This is not just a matter between rich CEOs and mostly rich shareholders. (Pension funds and middle-income people with 401(k)s also do own stock.)

Bloated CEO pay affects pay scales throughout the economy. If the CEO gets $30 million, the folks next in line likely get $10–15 million, and the third-tier executives may earn in the range of $1–2 million. Also, top executives in the non-profit sector also get bloated pay, often well over $1 million a year at universities and major charities.

By contrast, if CEOs were getting $2–$3 million a year, the next in line would likely be getting paychecks not much over $1 million, with the third tier settling for the high hundreds of thousands. And, the presidents of elite universities might also see paychecks in the high hundreds of thousands. And, if there was less pay for those at the top, there would be more pay for everyone else.

The point here is that this would not be a story of just saying we don’t like some people getting incredibly rich, while others get little (which may be the case), it would also be the story of getting the market to work better so that CEO pay reflects their actual performance, not their ability to take advantage of their insider position. There is no good argument for defending CEO pay that does not reflect performance unless you think it is a positive good that some people incredibly get rich while most workers get little benefit from the economy’s growth.

The Washington Post’s analysis of projected increases in the cost of health care plans in the exchanges created by the Affordable Care Act (ACA) is seriously confused. Paige Winfield Cunningham seems to think she found a contradiction between Democrats who minimized the importance of price increases during the Obama presidency, but now highlight smaller increases projected under the Trump administration. Rather than being a contradiction, this reflects confusion on Cunningham’s part.

The original premiums in the exchanges were lower than had been projected by the Congressional Budget Office prior to the bill’s passage. Insurers priced their plans too low either because they wanted to attract patients or they failed to predict the health condition of the people who signed up. By 2016, premiums had pretty much caught up with the original projections.

Even though the 7.0 percent rate of increase projected for the next decade is lower than the 2017 increase, it still implies that premiums will double in nominal terms and rise by more than 60 percent after adjusting for inflation over the next decade. If this projection proves accurate it means that the unsubsidized premiums will be unaffordable to all but the richest people.

For example, this projection implies that an unsubsidized silver plan would cost more than $11,000 (in 2018 dollars) to a single 50-year old in 2027. A 60-year-old would have to pay almost $17,000 for a silver plan. It is understandable that anyone concerned about affordable health care would not view this as a good story, even if they happened to be Republicans.

The Washington Post’s analysis of projected increases in the cost of health care plans in the exchanges created by the Affordable Care Act (ACA) is seriously confused. Paige Winfield Cunningham seems to think she found a contradiction between Democrats who minimized the importance of price increases during the Obama presidency, but now highlight smaller increases projected under the Trump administration. Rather than being a contradiction, this reflects confusion on Cunningham’s part.

The original premiums in the exchanges were lower than had been projected by the Congressional Budget Office prior to the bill’s passage. Insurers priced their plans too low either because they wanted to attract patients or they failed to predict the health condition of the people who signed up. By 2016, premiums had pretty much caught up with the original projections.

Even though the 7.0 percent rate of increase projected for the next decade is lower than the 2017 increase, it still implies that premiums will double in nominal terms and rise by more than 60 percent after adjusting for inflation over the next decade. If this projection proves accurate it means that the unsubsidized premiums will be unaffordable to all but the richest people.

For example, this projection implies that an unsubsidized silver plan would cost more than $11,000 (in 2018 dollars) to a single 50-year old in 2027. A 60-year-old would have to pay almost $17,000 for a silver plan. It is understandable that anyone concerned about affordable health care would not view this as a good story, even if they happened to be Republicans.

The New York Times ran a piece on a warning from the Internal Revenue Service that it would not allow plans to circumvent the new limits on the State and Local Tax (SALT) deduction by providing a credit for contributions to state-established charitable funds. At one point the piece told readers:

“The Treasury Department and the I.R.S. are worried that the workarounds could further balloon the cost of the tax cuts, which are projected to add more than $1 trillion to the national debt over a decade.”

NYT reporters must have some extraordinary mind-reading abilities if they can know what is really worrying the Treasury Department and IRS. The worries attributed to them here seem especially out of line with the known facts since the Trump administration and Republicans in Congress have shown zero concern in their behavior about the size of the deficit.

The New York Times ran a piece on a warning from the Internal Revenue Service that it would not allow plans to circumvent the new limits on the State and Local Tax (SALT) deduction by providing a credit for contributions to state-established charitable funds. At one point the piece told readers:

“The Treasury Department and the I.R.S. are worried that the workarounds could further balloon the cost of the tax cuts, which are projected to add more than $1 trillion to the national debt over a decade.”

NYT reporters must have some extraordinary mind-reading abilities if they can know what is really worrying the Treasury Department and IRS. The worries attributed to them here seem especially out of line with the known facts since the Trump administration and Republicans in Congress have shown zero concern in their behavior about the size of the deficit.

MarketWatch had a short piece reporting that Michael Woodford, one of the country’s most prominent macroeconomists, is now arguing that the Fed should actively look to stem the growth of asset bubbles like the housing bubble in the last decade. It points out that house prices have been rising rapidly in recent years. It also notes that Woodford argues the Fed should not distinguish between run-ups in house prices based on fundamentals and run-ups based on speculation.

As someone who advocated the Fed should counteract bubbles long before the crash of the housing bubble sank the economy, I am glad to see Woodford make this case. However, I think he is badly mistaken in arguing for using interest rate policy, rather than regulatory policy and public statements and information to try to sink a bubble. Also, it is very important to distinguish between a bubble-driven run-up in house prices and one driven by the fundamentals of the market.

Interest rates are a very inefficient tool for targeting an asset bubble. High enough interest rates will eventually burst the bubble, but they will also sink the economy. Bubbles are not likely to respond to modest increases in interest rates absent other measures from the Fed.

The effort to target rising housing prices, if they are driven by fundamentals (as is now the case), is likely to be self-defeating. Insofar as house prices are driven by fundamentals, it means that the best way to bring them down is by increasing supply. While this can be done through changing zoning policy at the local level, the Fed is not in a position to directly affect zoning. However, higher interest rates will reduce construction, making shortages of housing worse.

While higher rates will also eventually reduce demand by making house buying less affordable, this is a very indirect way of addressing the problem. It also means that it addresses a real shortage of housing by making it difficult for people to buy homes rather than increasing the supply. That doesn’t seem like good policy.

MarketWatch had a short piece reporting that Michael Woodford, one of the country’s most prominent macroeconomists, is now arguing that the Fed should actively look to stem the growth of asset bubbles like the housing bubble in the last decade. It points out that house prices have been rising rapidly in recent years. It also notes that Woodford argues the Fed should not distinguish between run-ups in house prices based on fundamentals and run-ups based on speculation.

As someone who advocated the Fed should counteract bubbles long before the crash of the housing bubble sank the economy, I am glad to see Woodford make this case. However, I think he is badly mistaken in arguing for using interest rate policy, rather than regulatory policy and public statements and information to try to sink a bubble. Also, it is very important to distinguish between a bubble-driven run-up in house prices and one driven by the fundamentals of the market.

Interest rates are a very inefficient tool for targeting an asset bubble. High enough interest rates will eventually burst the bubble, but they will also sink the economy. Bubbles are not likely to respond to modest increases in interest rates absent other measures from the Fed.

The effort to target rising housing prices, if they are driven by fundamentals (as is now the case), is likely to be self-defeating. Insofar as house prices are driven by fundamentals, it means that the best way to bring them down is by increasing supply. While this can be done through changing zoning policy at the local level, the Fed is not in a position to directly affect zoning. However, higher interest rates will reduce construction, making shortages of housing worse.

While higher rates will also eventually reduce demand by making house buying less affordable, this is a very indirect way of addressing the problem. It also means that it addresses a real shortage of housing by making it difficult for people to buy homes rather than increasing the supply. That doesn’t seem like good policy.

Want to search in the archives?

¿Quieres buscar en los archivos?

Click Here Haga clic aquí